How Persuasive Are Arguments Against Statewide Zoning Reform?

A leading scholar of state and local government argues that local governments’ need to regulate business should take priority over the state and national interests in lowering housing costs. Are his assumptions persuasive?

6 minute read

March 31, 2024, 9:00 AM PDT

By Michael Lewyn @mlewyn


Riverside, California

Orange Grove / Shutterstock

When I was arguing about housing policy on a listserv, one of my fellow participants cited an article by Richard Schragger of the University of Virginia’s law school. Schragger’s article criticizes attempts by state legislators to preempt local zoning policy.

While I’ve read (and critiqued) plenty of anti-housing articles, Schragger's article is unusual because it goes beyond the usual supply skeptic arguments and defends local control for reasons unrelated to housing costs. Because Schragger is one of our nation's leading authorities on local government issues, I expected to be intrigued by Professor Schragger’s argument — but I wasn’t persuaded. It seems to me that Schragger's arguments rest on a variety of questionable assumptions:

1. “We Have to Save Zoning To Save Local Control Over Everything Else.” Schragger admits that “certain kinds of local land use restrictions are pernicious” but that “Skepticism of localism in the land-use arena easily morphs into state dominance across all fields.” In other words, if states have too much control over land use law, they will limit local government in not-so-good ways as well.  

But as Schragger admits in the very next paragraph, state legislatures are already “keen to preempt local laws across large swaths of public policy.” It logically follows that local control over zoning won’t prevent states from micromanaging their cities. Schragger focuses on conservative state governments’ attempts to restrict left-leaning local policies. But as I have written elsewhere, blue state governments micromanage their cities as well; New York City’s ability to reform itself is limited in a wide variety of ways by state government. (For example, the state has imposed a floor area ratio cap that limits housing construction in the city). In other words, states will micromanage local governments even if they leave zoning untouched.

More specifically, Schragger argues that local governments should have unlimited land use power to extract concessions from businesses. For example, Schragger cites numerous examples of “the deployment of the land use permitting process to hold specific developers or incoming industries to higher wage and labor standards.” In other words, if groups favored by progressives (like unions) can get veto power over development and slow construction to a crawl, that’s actually a good thing because a few workers might get pay raises, or an environmental group can get a few policy concessions. But this does not seem like a particularly egalitarian result to me: Schragger admits that high-cost cities like New York tend to be among the most unequal cities in the U.S. (p. 188)-  and when the middle class is priced out of these cities, those cities become even more unequal. 

2. “We’ve Tried Statewide Land Reform And It Hasn’t Worked.” Schragger mentions that “In California and Oregon, state-level land-use regimes have been in place since the mid-to-late 1970s” (p. 152), yet those states are more expensive than most. But zoning reform in Oregon was focused more on limiting supply rather than increasing it; Oregon’s urban growth boundaries were designed to protect the state’s rural areas from suburban development, not to increase housing supply. Similarly, the California Coastal Commission exists to keep development away from California’s beaches, not to expand housing supply. In other words, 20th-century zoning reform was not designed to reduce housing costs, so to complain that it didn’t reduce housing costs isn't really relevant to whether a more deregulatory approach would have different results.

3. “Permissive Zoning Hasn’t Prevented Bad Stuff Unrelated To Housing Costs.” Schragger notes that in Houston, a city that has allowed more housing than most higher-cost cities, the “lack of zoning… has not benefited low-income communities, who have no effective means to protect themselves from the discriminatory siting of undesirable land uses.” The cheapest apartments in Houston, according to Zillow, rent for as little as $450. Don’t low-income people benefit from this?

4. “Even If Less Zoning Reduces Housing Costs, We Should Only Care About Poor People Who Never, Ever Move.” Schragger expresses “concerns that state-level land use reform will mostly redound to the benefit of investors and developers and not to those residents with limited resources who seek to afford to remain in place” (p. 129) (emphasis mine)- implying that residents with limited resources are only interested in “remaining in place” rather than moving to inexpensive housing. He adds that even though people “in the market for housing… are often priced out of high-cost urban markets” (emphasis mine), reformers “should be careful not to equate their interests with those of the working-class and especially minority poor” (id.), implying that working-class people aren’t "in the market for housing" or priced out of New York or San Francisco. Maybe I misunderstand Prof. Schragger here, but these passages sound to me like a suggestion that yuppies move around and benefit from lower rents, but poor people don’t move at all and don’t really need a low-cost housing market as long as they have rent control or public housing

But in fact, it is simply not the case that poverty equals stability. As Schragger himself writes a few pages later, "housing instability is an almost permanent state of affairs for a significant portion of urban residents." Census data show that lower-income households tend to move more than other Americans. This is common sense: if your income is low and unstable, you are more likely to be unable to pay rent than if you can afford to save. And at a time when American cities are struggling to house a tide of asylum applicants, the idea that poverty equals immobility is even more disconnected from reality than it was in 2021 when Schragger wrote this article. And if poor people move around a lot, it logically follows that they benefit from lower rents. 

Even if government came up with enough money to house everyone who was truly poor, a housing policy that disregards middle-class interests would not be ideal.  Suppose that a city has a housing market is divided between subsidized housing for the poor and a stagnant housing supply for the nonpoor. In such a city, the rich can afford high costs while the middle class gets priced out, thus creating a two-class city: hardly a result that progressives concerned about inequality should support.

5. “Zoning Doesn’t Matter Because It Reflects What Consumers Want.” Schragger notes that when Minneapolis allowed more triplexes, only three triplexes had been built. He therefore concludes that “existing zoning laws reflect consumer demand.” (p. 173). This seems like a bit of an overgeneralization. Sunbelt cities have generally allowed more housing in recent decades than high-cost cities like New York or San Francisco; does Schragger really think that this reflects lower demand for housing in San Francisco?

Schragger also throws in a few “supply skeptic” arguments; however, most of these seem to have been endlessly debated elsewhere (including in some of my own Planetizen posts). For example, Schragger writes that “market-oriented reforms- which tend to increase land values- can lead to higher, not lower prices.” But as I have pointed out elsewhere, land values have risen both in cities that add lots of housing and in cities that don’t add lots of housing, so I’m not sure there is a causal connection. Similarly, Schragger expresses concern that “the construction of mostly unoccupied housing in high-demand cities does little to increase the supply of affordable housing.” But Schragger’s own footnote on that page claims that only 4000 "ghost apartments" exist in New York City — a tiny amount in a city with 8 million people. (And as I have pointed out elsewhere, other data support the claim that consistently unoccupied apartments are rare). Schragger writes that increasing housing supply in a place with amenities “will only increase the population of amenity-seekers.” But as I have written elsewhere, the “induced demand” theory makes no sense. As I have written elsewhere, if more housing led to more demand, the places that allowed the most housing would have the most demand, and the highest housing costs.


Michael Lewyn

Michael Lewyn is a professor at Touro University, Jacob D. Fuchsberg Law Center, in Long Island. His scholarship can be found at http://works.bepress.com/lewyn.

portrait of professional woman

I love the variety of courses, many practical, and all richly illustrated. They have inspired many ideas that I've applied in practice, and in my own teaching. Mary G., Urban Planner

I love the variety of courses, many practical, and all richly illustrated. They have inspired many ideas that I've applied in practice, and in my own teaching.

Mary G., Urban Planner

Get top-rated, practical training

Bird's eye view of manufactured home park.

Manufactured Crisis: Losing the Nation’s Largest Source of Unsubsidized Affordable Housing

Manufactured housing communities have long been an affordable housing option for millions of people living in the U.S., but that affordability is disappearing rapidly. How did we get here?

March 25, 2025 - Shelterforce

U-Haul truck on road with blurred grassy roadside in background.

Americans May Be Stuck — But Why?

Americans are moving a lot less than they once did, and that is a problem. While Yoni Applebaum, in his highly-publicized article Stuck, gets the reasons badly wrong, it's still important to ask: why are we moving so much less than before?

March 27, 2025 - Alan Mallach

Rusty abandoned oil well and equipment with prickly pear cactus next to it in West Texas.

Using Old Oil and Gas Wells for Green Energy Storage

Penn State researchers have found that repurposing abandoned oil and gas wells for geothermal-assisted compressed-air energy storage can boost efficiency, reduce environmental risks, and support clean energy and job transitions.

March 31, 2025 - Pennsylvania State University

Downtown Los Angeles skyline viewed from a distance with freeway and trees in foreground.

Updating LA’s Tree Rules Could Bring More Shade to Underserved Neighborhoods

A new USC study finds that relaxing Los Angeles’ outdated tree planting guidelines could significantly expand urban tree canopy and reduce shade disparities in lower-income neighborhoods, though infrastructure investments are also needed.

15 minutes ago - USC Dornsife

Aerial view of Claifornia aqueduct with green orchard on one side.

California's Canal Solar Projects Aim to Conserve Resources and Expand Clean Energy

California’s Project Nexus has begun generating electricity from solar panels installed over irrigation canals, with researchers and state agencies exploring statewide expansion to conserve water and boost clean energy production.

1 hour ago - Turlock Journal

Close-up of older woman's hands resting on white modern heating radiator mounted on wall indoors.

HHS Staff Cuts Gut Energy Assistance Program

The full staff of a federal program that distributes heating and cooling assistance for low-income families was laid off, jeopardizing the program’s operations.

2 hours ago - The New York Times