And why it is wrong.

Recently, the federal government approved an environmental assessment for Manhattan’s congestion pricing program, allowing the program to go forward. By making driving more expensive, the program is likely to reduce pollution, injuries from traffic crashes, noise and automobile-related congestion in Manhattan, and will provide tax revenue for New York City’s public transit program.
Nevertheless, this program is quite controversial. One of the most interesting arguments against the program is that it is actually bad for Manhattan. For example, polymath and economist Tyler Cowen argues that to the extent congestion pricing succeeds in reducing congestion, it will reduce the flow of humans going into Manhattan, thus reducing revenue for Manhattan’s businesses, cultural attractions etc. This argument has some factual basis: even if most would-be drivers will be lured onto mass transit by congestion pricing, some number exceeding zero will avoid the city instead.
The argument rests on an assumption that a city is most appealing when automobile commuting is easy. But this assumption seems inconsistent with historical reality. This is the assumption that justified the “urban renewal” policies of the mid-20th century: city leaders used eminent domain to physically destroy city neighborhoods in order to build highways (and widen surface streets) leading to suburbia, so that suburbanites could drive to the city more easily. In addition, the same city leaders instituted minimum parking requirements so that suburbanites could park in the city more easily, thus turning downtowns into a wilderness of parking lots. If Cowen’s assumption had been correct, mid-century Americans would have flocked to renew old urban neighborhoods, since the cities were so easy to enter and exit. Instead, the highways and parking made it easier to commute from city to suburb, and thus encouraged commuters to move to suburbs. And after the commuters moved, jobs and businesses moved with them, and central cities declined. *
The least drivable and most congested cities, such as New York City, survived urban renewal with most of their population intact: New York lost only 11 percent of its population between 1950 and 1980, and its current population now exceeds its 1950 population. By contrast, low-congestion cities (other than those that annexed huge chunks of suburbia) suffered horribly: for example, St. Louis has lost over a third of its 1950 population.**In those cities, urban renewal was very, very successful at facilitating automobile commuting—as a result, it was very, very unsuccessful in renewing the city.
In sum, a “drivable” city is not necessarily a prosperous one. So if making cities like Manhattan easier to drive through doesn’t make them more appealing, it logically follows that making them harder to drive through won’t make them less appealing.
*Admittedly, highways were not the only cause of suburbanization. However, there is certainly some scholarly evidence of a causal relationship. Moreover, most other possible causes of suburbanization (rising crime, corruption, failed school integration, etc) existed in New York just as they existed in St. Louis or other declining cities.
**Can I prove that there is a causal relationship here? Because we don't know which cities were most congested in 1950 or 1970, it is hard to be sure. One might argue that New York is more congested only because it has not lost population. On the other hand, it seems to me as a matter of common sense that if it is easy for workers to live in the suburbs and drive downtown, they are more likely to live in the suburbs than if such commuting was more difficult.

Study: Maui’s Plan to Convert Vacation Rentals to Long-Term Housing Could Cause Nearly $1 Billion Economic Loss
The plan would reduce visitor accommodation by 25,% resulting in 1,900 jobs lost.

North Texas Transit Leaders Tout Benefits of TOD for Growing Region
At a summit focused on transit-oriented development, policymakers discussed how North Texas’ expanded light rail system can serve as a tool for economic growth.

Why Should We Subsidize Public Transportation?
Many public transit agencies face financial stress due to rising costs, declining fare revenue, and declining subsidies. Transit advocates must provide a strong business case for increasing public transit funding.

How to Make US Trains Faster
Changes to boarding platforms and a switch to electric trains could improve U.S. passenger rail service without the added cost of high-speed rail.

Columbia’s Revitalized ‘Loop’ Is a Hub for Local Entrepreneurs
A focus on small businesses is helping a commercial corridor in Columbia, Missouri thrive.

Invasive Insect Threatens Minnesota’s Ash Forests
The Emerald Ash Borer is a rapidly spreading invasive pest threatening Minnesota’s ash trees, and homeowners are encouraged to plant diverse replacement species, avoid moving ash firewood, and monitor for signs of infestation.
Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools
This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.
Planning for Universal Design
Learn the tools for implementing Universal Design in planning regulations.
City of Santa Clarita
Ascent Environmental
Institute for Housing and Urban Development Studies (IHS)
City of Grandview
Harvard GSD Executive Education
Toledo-Lucas County Plan Commissions
Salt Lake City
NYU Wagner Graduate School of Public Service
