Conventional planning tends to consider traffic congestion asignificant cost and roadway expansion the preferred solution. It evaluates transport system performance based on indicators such as roadway Level of Service (LOS) and peak-period traffic
Conventional planning tends to consider traffic congestion a significant cost and roadway expansion the preferred solution. It evaluates transport system performance based on indicators such as roadway Level of Service (LOS) and peak-period traffic speeds, and dedicates most transportation resources (road space and money) to roads and parking facilities. This results in predict and provide planning in which roadways are expanded to accommodate anticipated traffic, which creates a self-fulfilling prophecy by inducing additional vehicle use. Current congestion evaluation methods are crude and biased, resulting in excessive roadway capacity and a less diverse transportation system than is economically and socially optimal. My new report, Smart Congestion Relief: Comprehensive Analysis Of Traffic Congestion Costs and Congestion Reduction Benefits discusses these issues. Let me share highlights.
This is a timely issue. Motor vehicle travel grew steadily during the Twentieth Century so it made sense to devote significant resources to roadway expansion. During that period there was little risk of overbuilding since any additional road capacity would eventually fill. However, vehicle travel has peaked (see graph) and demand for alternatives is increasing due to demographic and economic trends including aging population, rising fuel prices, urbanization, health and environmental concerns, and changing consumer preferences. This requires more comprehensive evaluation that considers more impacts and options.
Conventional congestion evaluation tend to be biased in various ways, as summarized in the following table. For example, conventional evaluation recognizes that wider roads improve automobile access but ignore their tendency to reduce walking and cycling access (called the barrier effect), and it favors a hierarchical road system that has higher-speed arterials over a more connected road system that has lower travel speeds but shorter travel distances. As a result, mobility-based planning can result in congestion reduction strategies that reduce overall accessibility by creating sprawled, automobile-dependent communities where activities are widely dispersed and alternatives to driving are inferior.
Congestion Costing Biases, Impacts and Corrections
Type of Bias |
Planning Impacts |
Corrections |
Mobility-based planning measures congestion intensity rather than total congestion costs |
Favors roadway expansion over other transport improvements |
Measure overall accessibility, including per capita congestion costs |
Assumes that compact development increases congestion |
Encourage automobile-dependent sprawl over more compact, multi-modal infill development |
Recognize that smart growth policies can increase accessibility and reduce congestion costs |
Only considers impacts on motorists |
Favors driving over other modes |
Use multi-modal transport system performance indicators |
Estimates delay relative to free flow conditions (LOS A) |
Results in excessively high estimates of congestion costs |
Use realistic baselines (e.g., LOS C) when calculating congestion costs |
Applies relatively high travel time cost values |
Favors roadway expansion beyond what is really optimal |
Test willingness-to-pay for congestion reductions with road tolls |
Uses outdated fuel and emission models that exaggerate fuel savings and emission reductions |
Exaggerates roadway expansion economic and environmental benefits |
Use more accurate models |
Ignores congestion equilibrium and the additional costs of induced travel |
Exaggerates future congestion problems and roadway expansion benefits |
Recognize congestion equilibrium, and account for generated traffic and induced travel costs |
Funding and planning biases such as dedicated road funding and minimum parking requirements |
Makes road and parking improvements easier to implement than other types of transport improvements |
Apply least-cost planning, so transport funds can be used for the most cost-effective solution. Reform minimum parking requirements. |
Exaggerated roadway expansion economic productivity gains |
Encourages roadway expansion over other transport improvements |
Use critical analysis of congestion reduction economic benefits |
Considers congestion costs and congestion reduction objectives in isolation |
Favors roadway expansion over other congestion reduction strategies |
Use a comprehensive evaluation framework that considers all objectives and impacts |
This table summarizes common congestion costing biases, their impacts on planning decisions, and corrections for more comprehensive and objective congestion costs.
In recent years transportation professionals have started to develop better tools for evaluating overall accessibility, and multi-modal performance indicators, which allow more comprehensive evaluation of transportation problems and improvement strategies.
Conventional urban transport planning tends to consider traffic congestion the dominant planning problem, but more comprehensive and objective analysis indicates that traffic congestion is actually a moderate cost overall – larger than some but smaller than others – and roadway expansion is generally less effective and beneficial overall than other congestion reduction strategies.
Studies such as the Texas Transportation Institute's Urban Mobility Report conclude that traffic congestion is a major economic cost and roadway expansion can increase economic productivity but these are probably exaggerations. As Professor Eric Dumbaugh pointed out in a recent Atlantic Cities magazine article, Rethinking the Economics of Traffic Congestion, economic productivity tends to increase with congestion. This does not actually indicate that increasing congestion causes economic development, but it shows that traffic congestion is overall a minor cost that is usually offset by the economic efficiency gains of the increased accessibility provided by more compact and multi-modal development. For example, a business located in a city center has far more potential employees, partners and customers available within a half-hour trip, despite traffic congestion.
Some congestion reduction strategies provide significant co-benefits. Improving alternative modes (particularly high quality public transit), improved roadway connectivity, pricing reforms and smart growth development polices reduce traffic congestion and help achieve other planning objectives. These strategies do not necessarily eliminate congestion, in fact, they may increase congestion intensity, but they can improve overall accessibility and reduce per capita congestion costs.
Despite frequent complaints about traffic congestion there appears to be insufficient willingness-to-pay for major urban roadway expansion, nor sufficient political support for congestion pricing, indicating that motorists do not really consider it a major problem. Financing highway expansion using other funding sources is economically inefficient and unfair because it forces people who don't use the added capacity to subsidize people who do. Excessive estimates of congestion costs and congestion reduction benefits tend to contradict transport equity objectives: they favor motorists over non-motorists and reduce the quality of transport options available to people who are physically, economically and socially disadvantaged.
This is not to suggest that driving is bad or that roadways should never be improved. However, when all impacts and options are considered, highway expansion is significantly more costly and less beneficial, and alternative congestion reduction strategies are often better, than indicated by conventional project economic evaluations. It is important that decision makers and the general public understand these issues when evaluating solutions to congestion problems.
For More Information
Md Aftabuzzaman, Graham Currie and Majid Sarvi (2011), "Exploring The Underlying Dimensions Of Elements Affecting Traffic Congestion Relief Impact Of Transit," Cities, Vol. 28, Is. 1, February, Pages 36-44.
Robert L. Bertini (2005), You Are the Traffic Jam: An Examination of Congestion Measures, Department of Civil & Environmental Engineering, Portland State University, presented at the Transportation Research Board Annual Meeting.
Joe Cortright (2010), Driven Apart: How Sprawl is Lengthening Our Commutes and Why Misleading Mobility Measures are Making Things Worse, CEOs for Cities (www.ceosforcities.org).
Eric Dumbaugh (2012), Rethinking the Economics of Traffic Congestion, Atlantic Cities, 1 June 2012.
J. Richard Kuzmyak (2012), Land Use and Traffic Congestion, Report 618, Arizona Department of Transportation.
John N. LaPlante (2007), "Strategies for Addressing Congestion," ITE Journal, Vol. 77, No. 7 (www.ite.org), July 2007, pp. 20-22.
Todd Litman (2011), "Smart Traffic Congestion Reductions: Comprehensive Analysis of Congestion Costs and Congestion Reduction Benefits," Traffic Infra Tech, Oct-Nov 2011, Vol. 2, No. 2, pp. 42-46 (www.trafficinfratech.com).
Todd Litman (2012), Smart Congestion Relief: Comprehensive Analysis Of Traffic Congestion Costs and Congestion Reduction Benefits, presented at the Transportation Research Board Annual Meeting.
Nelson\Nygaard (2006), Traffic Reduction Strategies Study, for the City of Pasadena.

What ‘The Brutalist’ Teaches Us About Modern Cities
How architecture and urban landscapes reflect the trauma and dysfunction of the post-war experience.

USDOT Revokes Approval for NYC Congestion Pricing
Despite the administration’s stated concern for the “working class,” 85 percent of Manhattan commuters use public transit to enter the city.

Tiny House Villages for Addressing Homelessness: An Interview with Yetimoni Kpeebi
One researcher's perspective on the potential of tiny homes and owner-built housing as one tool to fight the housing crisis.

Preserving Altadena’s Trees: A Community Effort to Save a Fire-Damaged Landscape
In the wake of the Eaton Fire, Altadena Green is working to preserve fire-damaged but recoverable trees, advocating for better assessment processes, educating homeowners, and protecting the community’s urban canopy from unnecessary removal.

The VW Bus is Back — Now as an Electric Minivan
Volkswagen’s ID. Buzz reimagines its iconic Bus as a fully electric minivan, blending retro design with modern technology, a 231-mile range, and practical versatility to offer a stylish yet functional EV for the future.

Investigation Reveals Just How Badly California’s Homeless Shelters are Failing
Fraud, violence, death, and chaos follow a billion dollar investment in a temporary solution that is proving ineffective.
Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools
This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.
Planning for Universal Design
Learn the tools for implementing Universal Design in planning regulations.
Economic & Planning Systems, Inc.
UCLA Lewis Center for Regional Policy Studies
Mpact (formerly Rail~Volution)
Chaddick Institute at DePaul University
City of Piedmont, CA
Great Falls Development Authority, Inc.
HUDs Office of Policy Development and Research
